Bank Fees, Drought Assistance – Doorstop Interview, Strathcona Junior School Campus, Canterbury, Melbourne
May 20, 2005OECD Upbeat on Australia’s Economic Outlook
May 24, 2005OFFICIAL LAUNCH OF DR ANDREW SOUTHCOTT’S JOURNAL
– LOOKING FORWARD
SENATE ALCOVE, PARLIAMENT HOUSE, CANBERRA
WEDNESDAY, 22 JUNE 2005
What a great pleasure it is to be here to launch the journal of ideas Looking
Forward. At the outset, I want to pay tribute to Andrew Southcott for his
editorship of this journal. Andrew is one of the new breed of Liberals:- highly
qualified as a medical doctor; a sportsman; and an MP:- a renaissance man. And
now of course he is a distinguished editor, judging by the contributors that
you have here Andrew, people of the calibre and capacity of Senator Nick Minchin,
Nick Park, Dr David Kemp, my old politics professor – David Kemp was my politics
professor and Andrew Theophanous was my tutor – Michael Keenan who makes a distinguished
contribution and David Crawshay.
Looking Forward of course was the name of the pamphlet published by
the Victorian IPA and written by C.D “Ref” Kemp. Robert Menzies
called together a meeting of the non-Labor organisations, first here in Canberra
in 1944 and subsequently in Albury to put together a non-Labor political force
which would be capable of contesting the 1946 election. At that conference –
and we can see a picture of those who attended, we believe this is the Albury
conference – Menzies concluded by reading a quote from the pamphlet Looking
Forward which has been authored by “Ref” Kemp.
Australia was then going through the Second World War and the war was drawing
to a close. A great deal of thought was being given to the nature of post-war
reconstruction and the way in which Australian society would be organised. There
were two contending schools. The first was the incumbent Labor Party view which
in order to fight the war had extended control over the economy quite considerably,
and wished to maintain it, with a very large government role in the post-war
reconstruction. The second was that put together by Menzies who believed that
Australia’s future would be a private enterprise economy.
Chifley won the 1946 election. In 1947 the Chifley Government introduced legislation
to nationalise the banks. That legislation was passed. Under legislation passed
by the Commonwealth Parliament all the banks were to be nationalised and the
Government would take control of the banking sector. I imagine that in 1947
banks were as unpopular as they are today and that to stand-up and to defend
the private banking system against nationalisation would have taken a great
deal of courage.
The issue could not be fought on the issue of banking alone, but on the greater
principle of what role the State should play in the post-war economy and what
role private enterprise would play. As we know, the bank nationalisation legislation
was struck down by the High Court which was affirmed by the Privy council. But
the Chifley Government was not finished yet. In 1948, through referendum, it
sought the power to control rents and prices. It was defeated in that referendum.
But if those suite of measures had remained in place, by 1948 the Government
would have controlled prices, rents, banking. It would have been an economy
looking suspiciously like the command economies of Eastern Europe.
The great electoral contest in 1949 was between two alternate visions for the
Australian nation. One was price control, rent control, bank nationalisation
and the other was a system of private enterprise, private savings and market
economics. The 1949 election was the great turning point for Australia. If the
Liberal Party had not been elected in 1949, Australia would have gone much further
down the socialist route, which took hold in Britain after the war, which had
taken hold in New Zealand before the war, and our economic potential would have
been much more limited.
It is true that Chifley had an obsession with banks and hated them. But the
moves that he put together on behalf of the Labor Party were very much in accord
with the objective for which the Labor Party was founded. Let me remind you,
to this day, the objective of the Australian Labor Party is:- “the democratic
socialisation of industry, production, distribution and exchange to the extent
necessary to eliminate exploitation and other anti-social features in these
fields.” That was the objective in 1949, it is still the objective today.
The difference is that in 1949 apparently the Labor Party believed it.
But this is Labor’s problem. Today, the Labor Party has at its heart
an objective which it no longer believes in. And because it no longer believes
in its central founding objective, there is a hollowness to its ideas and to
its political platform. When the question is asked, what does the Labor Party
stand for, the answer you cannot give is that it stands for its constitutional
objective. And that just invites the further question. If we know what it doesn’t
stand for, can we answer the question of what it does stand for?
Now, as you know I enjoy reading books. I was quite taken with a book about
postcodes which was recently authored by one of the Members of the House of
Representatives. In the book called Postcodes, the author sets out five
principles that the Labor Party will follow in relation to economic management.
One, ensure the Budget remains in balance over the cycle:- the objective we
laid down in 1996. Two, have an effective monetary policy with an independent
Reserve Bank:- the policy we laid down in 1996. Three, spending through savings
and re-prioritisation rather than debt:- a policy we have pursued since 1996.
Four, combating price inflation through pro-competitive reform policy:- which
we have pursued since 1996. Five, investing in the productive capacity of the
economy with emphasis on productivity, participation and population:- the law
of the three P’s which the Government laid down in 2002.
The Labor economic policy as put forward in this book is to follow Coalition
policy. But why would you vote for a Labor Party to implement Coalition policy?
Surely, the voter would be better advised to vote for the Party that not only
laid it down but in its heart of hearts believes it.
As we look back on the election of 1949, the great economic struggle was between
market economics and nationalisation or the command economy. The international
argument over this raged for decades but was decisively ended in 1989 with the
fall of the Berlin Wall. For the Liberal Party, it managed to be on the right
side of history. The Liberal economic idea triumphed. We can see that clearly
today but in a way which was not so clear in 1949. This gives the Liberal Party
great moral authority in relation to economics and economic policy.
Now since the outcome of the 2004 election, Labor has changed its tune somewhat
and now says it stands in the tradition of the market economy and market economics
as represented by the Hawke and Keating era.
You should give tribute where tribute is deserved, and I always have. The Hawke
– Keating Government moved to a floating exchange rate – a very significant
reform and one which they were supported in doing by the Liberal Party –
and the reduction of tariffs – another very significant reform and one
they were supported in doing by the Liberal Party.
But you would hardly join Labor if your principle motivation on economic policy
was to promote markets, competition and private enterprise. It would be a long
way home to that policy objective, to join a Party whose constitutional objective
is “the democratic socialisation of industry production, distribution
and exchange.”
It would be possible, I suppose, to promote the Holy Roman Catholic faith by
joining the Presbyterian Church of Northern Ireland – but it would be
a long way home.
It would be possible to work for a Collingwood Premiership by joining the Essendon
Football Club – but it would be a long way home.
It would be possible to seek to promote open markets, low tariffs, enterprise
bargaining and privatisation by joining the Labor Party but it is not the most
immediately obvious way to support those objectives. When Labor claims that
this is what it believes in there is a hollow ring to its declaration.
Now we who do believe in a private enterprise economy, open markets, enterprise
bargaining, competition and have chosen a shorter way home. But we must never
rest. We must always be on our guard because the threats to open markets and
competition will come now in different guises. It won’t come in the guise
of nationalisation, that has had its day. But it might come to us in the guise
of monopoly suppliers who want protection from competition. It might come to
us in the guise of marketing schemes where people’s produce is appropriated.
It might come to us in the guise of arbitration which infringes an individual’s
right to negotiate their price of labour. The challenge to the open market and
private enterprise will continue to come but in more concealed ways. We must
be on our guard.
Adam Smith famously said in The Wealth of Nations: “People of
the same trade seldom meet together even for merriment and diversion but the
conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public or in some contrivance
to raise prices”. Every time I see a lobbyist walking the halls of Parliament
House I think of that quote. We in the Liberal Party must always be on our guard.
We were on the right side of history in 1949. We were on the right side of
history in the great argument between the market economy and the command economy.
Now today what we as Liberals have to do better, is to explain our social policy.
And if a journal of ideas can do that then it will add considerably to the intellectual
force of our political party.
Because we are Liberals we are wary of State power. We know that individual
freedom often has to be defended against the State. We are suspicious of grand
plans in social engineering. Sometimes our social policy looks less visionary
because we don’t believe in the grand schemes. A Liberal would never support
the planning schemes of an Albert Speer. We would be too worried about individual
property rights and individual dislocation. We would be too worried about the
impacts on families and communities. Our social policy will always be wary of
Government intervention and respectful of the non-Government institutions of
society. We will always defend non-Government institutions. Why? Because we
see them as a protection against the State. We see the family as a protection
against State power, we see the church as a protection against State power,
we like those institutions because they can defend the individual against State
power and maximise human liberty.
[Ringing of the Bells]
I bring my speech to an end, before I reach my crescendo by wishing well to
this publication Looking Forward. This is a journal of ideas. Our Party
is a Party of ideas. We want to see those ideas flourish. We were on the right
side of ideas in the past and we want to be on the right side in the future.
It is a great pleasure to launch this magazine.